IN THE MATTER OF:
Porcelain-on-steel cookware from Mexico
(Continued)
2. Profit-Sharing
Mexican law directs Cinsa to distribute ten percent of its taxable income
to its employees at the close of any fiscal year during which the Company
has earned a profit through its operations. Cinsa recorded profits during
the two fiscal periods subject to the Department’s review. Cinsa did not
include profit-sharing payments as part of its reported labor costs for
COP or CV. In the fifth administrative review, however, Commerce adjusted
Cinsa’s COP and CV to include mandatory profit-sharing payments to its
employees. 60 Fed. Reg. at 2378.
Cinsa argues that such payments should not be included as labor costs
in COP or CV because they are profit-based distributions unrelated to the
manufacture of the products at issue. The Department defends its methodology
as a reasonable exercise of agency discretion, maintaining that the payments
made to employees are analogous to wages or other compensation to labor.
The antidumping statute offers no explicit guidance about whether profit-sharing
expenses should be added to COP or CV. See 19 U.S.C.A. § 1677b(b)(3)
(1994 & Supp. 1996); 19 U.S.C.A. § 1677b(e) (1994 & Supp.
1996). Moreover, the Department’s regulations, although specifically excluding
"profit" from COP, do not address the treatment of mandatory profit-sharing
payments. See 19 C.F.R. § 353.51© (including in COP "the cost
of materials, fabrication, and general expenses, but excluding profit,
incurred in producing such or similar merchandise"). Given the absence
of legislative or regulatory guidance, the Panel agrees with the Department
that its choice of methodology regarding profit-sharing payments is entitled
to substantial deference. See Koyo Seiko Co. v. United States, 36 F.3d
1565, 1570 (Fed. Cir. 1994). The assignment of profit-sharing expenses
to COP and CV calculations is consistent with the Department’s administrative
practice. See Oil Country Tubular Goods from Austria, 60 Fed. Reg. 33,551,
33,557 (1995). See also Certain Corrosion Resistant Carbon Steel Flat Products
and Certain Cut-to-Length Carbon Steel Plate from Mexico, 58 Fed. Reg.
37,192, 37,193 (1993); Certain Hot-Rolled Carbon Steel Flat Products, Certain
Cold-Rolled Carbon Steel Flat Products, Certain Corrosion Resistant Carbon
Steel Flat Products, and Certain Cut-to-Length Steel Plate from Canada,
58 Fed. Reg. 37,099, 37,113 (1993); Certain Hot-Rolled Lead and Bismuth
Carbon Steel Products from Germany, 57 Fed. Reg. 44,551, 44,553 (1992).
However, no court has addressed the reasonableness of the Department’s
methodology. In determining COP and CV, Commerce does not include, as a
general principle, "income or expenses that are unrelated to the product’s
manufacture." Television Receivers, Monochrome and Color, from Japan, 56
Fed. Reg. 56,189, 56,192 (1991). Thus, the issue is whether mandatory profit-sharing
payments are expenses related to the production of Cinsa’s products.
The parties dispute the critical attributes of a company’s cost of production.
Commerce argues that the appropriate focus of inquiry is the recipient
of corporate payments. Because, in the case of Cinsa, employees receive
these payments, they are properly categorized as a cost of labor and, thus,
an appropriate component of COP and CV. Cinsa, by contrast, asks this Panel
to consider only the process for determining the amount of profit-sharing
due to employees. Cinsa argues that, like income taxes and dividend payments,
profit-sharing is an income-based expense derived solely from the amount
of profit a company enjoys in a given fiscal year and is independent of
the costs of production or labor.
In fact, profit-sharing payments are hybrid transfers of value, bearing
certain similarities to wages and transfers such as interest expenses on
one hand and to income taxes and dividend payments on the other. Wages
and interest payments constitute part of COP and CV. Income taxes and dividend
distributions do not. See Oil Country Tubular Goods from Austria, 60 Fed.
Reg. at 33,557; High Information Content Flat Panel Displays and Display
Glass Therefor from Japan, 56 Fed. Reg. 32,376, 32,392 (1991); Timken Co.
v. United States, 852 F. Supp. 1040, 1049 (Ct. Int’l Trade 1994). The Panel
must determine which type of payment exhibits the closest resemblance to
the profit-sharing payments at issue. Cinsa argues that profit-sharing
payments are not a labor cost because they are not tied to hours worked
or units produced and are, thus, unrelated to production of the subject
merchandise. But, as the Department has observed, other forms of employee
compensation included in COP and CV, such as group health insurance, payroll
taxes, and company-paid life insurance, are tied neither to hours worked
nor to the amount produced.
Cinsa also argues that profit-sharing payments are more like dividends
than wages. Given the risk that employees assume in any profit-sharing
plan, this is not an unreasonable argument. Given imperfect information,
workers who accept reduced wages in exchange for profit-sharing payments
risk discovering at year-end that the return on their "investment" of labor
will not meet their expectations.
Profit-sharing payments are distinct from dividends in several key respects,
however. First, as suggested, profit-sharing payments represent a legal
obligation of the firm, contingent only upon whether the firm posts a profit
for the fiscal year. Second, and most important, the right to participate
in profit-sharing conveys no ownership rights in the company. Profit-sharing
is a payment to a productive factor in the production process, not a payment
of profit to the owners of the firm. 3
Moreover, accounting principles distinguish between profit-sharing payments
and dividends. Like income taxes, profit-sharing payments appear as an
expense featured on the income statement. By contrast, dividends affect
only the equity side of the balance sheet and do not originate on the income
statement. Oil Country Tubular Goods from Austria, 60 Fed. Reg. at 33,557.
On the balance sheet, profit is the value remaining after reductions to
income, including profit-sharing and income taxes. Dividends are true distributions
of profits paid to the owners of the company, and "profit" is explicitly
excluded from COP calculations under 19 C.F.R. § 353.51©. Thus,
the Department’s disparate treatment of profit-sharing and dividends accords
with fundamental accounting principles.
The argument on which Cinsa places greatest reliance is that profit-sharing
payments are analogous to income taxes and, therefore, like income taxes,
should be excluded from COP and CV. In explaining why income taxes are
not included in COP or CV, the Department has consistently cited the fact
that income taxes are based on the level of income that a corporation realizes.
E.g., High Information Content Flat Panel Displays and Display Glass Therefor
from Japan, 56 Fed. Reg. at 32,392 ("Department does not consider income
taxes based on the aggregate profit/loss of the corporation to be a cost
of producing the product."); Color Picture Tubes from Japan, 55 Fed. Reg.
37,915, 37,925 (1990); Television Receivers, Monochrome and Color, from
Japan, 54 Fed. Reg. 13,917, 13,928 (1989). Cinsa notes correctly, however,
that this does not distinguish income taxes from profit-sharing because
both constitute mandatory payments that are tied to a firm’s fiscal results. 4
Profit-sharing payments are unlike income taxes in two critically important
ways, however. First, profit-sharing payments are paid to labor. Thus,
unlike income taxes paid to the government, profit-sharing payments flow
directly to a factor of production. Second, because workers receive these
payments, the firm may use the expected, risk-discounted value of future
profit-sharing payments to maintain its worker compensation at the market-clearing
level, thus avoiding any increase in its cost of capital.
It is reasonable to assume that, rather than seeing its cost of capital
and, ultimately, its marginal costs rise, a rational firm will attempt
to keep its employee compensation levels at the market-clearing level,
and will attempt to pass the cost of profit-sharing on to those workers
who benefit from it—rather than to shareholders.
The firm and its workers will negotiate wage contracts in light of the
firm’s legal obligation to make profit-sharing payments. The firm’s projected
profits for the coming period, as well as the chance that such profits
will be greater or less than actual profits, should play a role in determining
the fixed wage.
In short, despite similarity in the methods for calculating profit-sharing
payments and income taxes, these two obligations differ fundamentally.
Profit-sharing is paid to labor, a factor of production. Income taxes are
paid to the government, which is not a factor in the production process.
Although both income taxes and profit-sharing payments are mandatory and
based upon the firm’s year-end results, their basic purpose and effect
are sufficiently dissimilar to make the Department’s disparate treatment
of them in its COP and CV methodology a reasonable administrative action.
There is one difficulty with the preceding analysis that must be acknowledged.
Firms and workers should consider only the expected value of profit-sharing
payments, discounted for risk, in determining fixed wages. Commerce, however,
bases its COP calculations on actual profit-sharing payments.
In any given year, a firm’s actual profit-sharing payments almost certainly
will differ from the expected amount that was considered in setting fixed
wages and prices. Nevertheless, because Cinsa has not challenged Commerce’s
action on this basis, and because the Department’s use of actual profit-sharing
payments does not strike us as prima facie unreasonable, the Panel upholds
Commerce’s methodology. Cinsa also argues that Commerce counted profit-sharing
payments twice by including them in the CV calculations. This argument
adds nothing to Cinsa’s other contentions. The Panel has determined that
profit-sharing payments are not part of the firm’s profit, as that term
is understood according to general accounting principles. The "profit"
included in CV represents the amount that remains after reductions to income,
such as those taken for profit-sharing and income taxes. Thus, the Department’s
decision to include profit-sharing payments and an amount for profit in
CV did not result in double counting. 5
The Panel finds that Commerce made a reasonable determination to characterize
profit-sharing as a cost of labor and to include it in COP and CV in the
fifth administrative review.
3. Cap Upon Interest Income Offset at the Amount of Interest Expense
During the period of review Commerce, according to established policy,
calculated Cinsa’s financial expenses for addition to COP and CV by referring
to the financial expenses of Cinsa’s parent company, Grupo Industrial Saltillo,
S.A. de C.V. ("GIS"). GIS’s short-term interest income exceeded its interest
expense, resulting in net financial income for the company. However, in
its COP and CV calculations, Commerce entered a zero amount for interest
expense, thus disregarding the excess interest income. The Department’s
reasons for imposing a cap upon the use of interest income follow:
"It is the Department’s normal practice to allow short-term interest
income to offset financing costs only up to the amount of such financing
costs. The Department reduces interest expense by the amount of short-term
income to the extent finance costs are included in COP. Using total short-term
interest income in excess of interest expense to reduce production cost,
as suggested by Cinsa, would permit companies with large short-term investment
activity to sell their products below the COP." 60 Fed. Reg. at 2379, Pub.
Doc. 69 (citations omitted). Cinsa alleges that the Department’s decision
to ignore all excess short-term interest income was arbitrary and not supported
by substantial evidence. Cinsa argues that it is inconsistent to treat
short-term interest income that exceeds interest expense differently from
that which does not.
Short- term interest income has been considered by Commerce and the
Court of International Trade to finance production and therefore to be
a variable in the COP/CV calculations. Cinsa argues that this is true whether
the interest income exceeds interest expense or not. The income still remains
a component of financial expense.
The Department’s position is that the purpose of COP and CV is to calculate
cost. One element of cost is interest expense. Once short-term interest
income has reduced interest expense to zero, it would be unreasonable to
use excess interest income to offset other unrelated actual expenses. To
do so might mean that certain companies with large short-term investment
capabilities could sell at less than COP because their actual costs would
be reduced by interest. The Court of International Trade considered the
Department’s interest-income offset policy in general and stated that:
"[T]his Court finds that neither 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(e) [constructed
value] or 19 C.F.R. § 353.51© [cost of production] precludes
the ITA from making necessary adjustments for various sources of income
and expenses in its calculations of constructed value and COP. The starting
point for [Commerce] in its calculations of constructed value and COP is
to determine as accurately as possible the true cost to the respondent
of manufacturing the subject merchandise. This requires that offsets be
made for such sources of income as the sale of scrap left over from the
production process and various types of short-term interest income which
is used in the firms’ manufacturing operations." Timken Co. v. United States,
852 F. Supp. 1040, 1048-49 (Ct. Int’l Trade 1994).
The court thus affirmed the offset of certain income, ruling that nothing
in the relevant statute and regulation precluded such action. The court
also approved the Department’s central focus on calculating the actual
cost of manufacturing. The court did not address and has not addressed
in other cases, the issue of how the income should 6
be offset and whether a certain type of income can be used to offset any
cost of production in addition to the one to which it is most logically
related.
The Panel concludes from its review of the statute, regulations and
court precedent that nothing in the relevant law invalidates the Department’s
interest-capping policy. The Panel next turns to the Department’s administrative
decisions to determine if the policy is arbitrary, inconsistent with past
practice, or unreasonable.
All parties agree that Commerce has followed the income capping policy
for some time. Most determinations merely state the policy without explanation.
However, in 7 addition
to the reasoning given in the decision under review, Commerce has discussed
its reasons in several other decisions.
In Steel Wire Rope From Korea, 58 Fed. Reg. 11,029, 11,038 (1993), Commerce
explained the policy as follows:
"Short-term interest income related to production is an offset to interest
expense, not to COP and, therefore, can only be used to reduce total interest
expense to not less than zero." In Portable Electric Typewriters from Japan,
56 Fed. Reg. 736 58,031, 58,040 (1991) (Comment 8), Commerce explained
that "[W]e allowed the offset of interest income against interest expense
only to the extent of interest expense. Interest income which exceeds interest
expense represents Brother’s involvement in investment activities which
are not required for daily manufacturing operations. The interest income
is not related to production, and, therefore, may not be an offset against
other production costs."
Finally, in the fourth administrative review of Cinsa’s cooking ware,
Commerce stated that "The Department does not reduce production cost by
the excess because income derived from long-term investments is unrelated
to the production of the subject merchandise . . . . Using total short-term
interest income to reduce production cost, as suggested by CINSA, would
permit companies with large short-term investment activity to sell their
products below the cost of production and also avoid the full imposition
of antidumping duties." Porcelain-On-Steel Cooking Ware From Mexico, 58
Fed. Reg. 43,327, 43,332 (1993) (citation omitted).
The Panel finds that the Department’s policy as articulated in the final
results is not inconsistent with prior administrative decisions and that
it is not unreasonable or arbitrary in its application. Commerce has used
different language to explain its policy in the various administrative
determinations, but its consistent position is that excess interest income
is related to investment activities, not to production costs. To apply
that excess to production costs would distort a company’s actual costs.
Short-term interest income is relevant to determining whether a company
has interest expenses. Since money is fungible, it would not be accurate
to charge a company with interest expense if, in fact, it also enjoyed
short-term interest income during the same period. That income, however,
does not itself become a cost or lessen the burden of other costs. Regardless
of how much excess interest income there is, labor will still cost a certain
amount, so will materials and factory overhead.
Moreover, although a company may have short-term investments related
to the daily operations of the company, it is not clear that the full amount
of the return on that investment is needed for the production of the subject
merchandise. In contrast, interest expense is surely a cost necessary for
the daily business operation of the company.
Otherwise, a firm would not have incurred it. If the extra interest
income is allocated to costs, then a company could arbitrarily subsidize
a product by realizing financial activities not necessarily related to
the production of the subject merchandise and the COP/CV calculations would
be distortive. Thus, the Panel does not find it unreasonable or arbitrary
for Commerce to limit the interest offset.
4. Addition of the Full Amount of IVA Collected on Home Market Sales
to COP
As Cinsa reported to Commerce, all of its home market sales included
in the invoice price an amount for Mexico’s value added tax, the "Impuestos
Valor Agregado" ("IVA"). In addition, Cinsa reported to Commerce the actual
amount of IVA that it paid on inputs used in the production of subject
merchandise. No IVA is charged on labor, fixed overhead costs, or other
items of COP such as selling, general and administrative costs and financial
expenses. The amount of IVA paid on inputs is less than the amount charged
in the sales price.
When Commerce tested Cinsa’s home market prices against the COP, it
included the same amount of IVA in COP as was in the home market price,
rather than the amount of IVA actually paid on inputs. Commerce explained
its action as follows:
" Value added taxes are paid on inputs and, therefore, are costs incurred
in production. Upon the sale of the product, value added taxes are reimbursed
to CINSA by the ultimate consumer. Any amount of tax which is in excess
of the amount reimbursed is payable to the Mexican government. The Department’s
calculations must reflect the economic reality that CINSA does not receive
a benefit from collecting and paying IVA. Therefore, because COP is compared
to home market price which includes the entire IVA paid, to be neutral,
our calculations of COP must take into account the entire IVA paid (a portion
of which is paid on the inputs, and the remainder of which is due to the
government)." 60 Fed. Reg. at 2380.
Cinsa originally argued that the COP statute expressly requires the
construction of "all costs" of production. 19 U.S.C. 1677b(b) (1994 and
Supp. 1996). Commerce arguably overstated Cinsa’s IVA costs, and thus its
COP, by including the larger amount of IVA charged on home market sales
in the COP calculation. Cinsa argued that Commerce must follow the express
language of the statute and cannot alter the statutory scheme to achieve
"tax neutrality." In Cinsa’s reply and subsequently at oral argument, the
company referred to a recent opinion by the Court of Appeals for the Federal
Circuit approving Commerce’s approach to tax neutrality in making adjustments
for value added taxes under another statutory provision. Federal Mogul
Corp. v. United States, 63 F.3d 1572 (Fed. Cir. 1995). Cinsa suggested
that the Panel could remand the issue to Commerce to adopt a tax-neutral
treatment of the IVA. According to Cinsa, the method adopted by Commerce
in the final results is not tax-neutral. Two tax-neutral approaches would
be to add the absolute amount of IVA paid by Cinsa on production inputs
to both the COP and the home market sales price or to strip the IVA out
of both sides of the equation.
In Federal Mogul Corp. v. United States, supra, the Court of Appeals
considered the Department’s numerous attempts to adjust purchase price
pursuant to 19 U.S.C. § 1677a(d) by value added taxes which are included
in the exporter’s home market sales price. Various methods to make tax-neutral
adjustments had been tried and found by the reviewing court not to satisfy
statutory language. Ultimately, Commerce simply added the tax amount included
in the home market sales price to purchase price. The Court of International
Trade still found this method statutorily deficient.
The Court of Appeals reversed, concluding:
"Commerce’s long-standing policy of attempting tax-neutrality in its
administration of [the statutory provision] is not precluded by the language
of § 1677a, nor do we find the particular proposed methodology to
be an unreasonable way to pursue that policy in light of the statutory
language." 63 F.3d at 1580. 8
Similarly this Panel finds that nothing in the relevant statute prevents
Commerce from treating the IVA in a tax-neutral manner. All parties, moreover,
apparently agree that a tax-neutral method is acceptable. The Panel agrees
with Commerce’s explanation of the effect of the IVA. The firm collects
IVA from each sale that the firm makes and this amount is given back to
the government. The firm, however, subtracts from its IVA payment to the
government, the amount of IVA the firm paid on its inputs. Because of this
subtraction, it is as if Cinsa did not incur those IVA expenses on inputs.
If the home market price includes the full IVA received from the firms,
then to be neutral, it is reasonable for Commerce to add the full amount
of IVA due on sales to the COP. Since the IVA revenue will be transferred
completely to the government, it is like an expense that the firm has to
incur.
At oral argument, Commerce submitted that there was no difference in
Cinsa’s margin of dumping if Commerce substituted either one of the tax-neutral
methods proposed by Cinsa for the method actually used by Commerce in the
final results. Counsel for Cinsa argued that there was a difference; it
would be tax-neutral to add the IVA imposed on inputs to COP and to home
market price, but it was not tax-neutral to add the full-price-based amount
of IVA to both sides.
The Panel is not persuaded that there is a difference in results among
any of the three methods suggested. Each one appears to achieve tax-neutrality
without changing Cinsa’s dumping margin. The Panel, therefore, affirms
the tax-neutral result without discussion of whether one method is preferable
to another.
5. Pricing Differences Attributable to Product Color
Cinsa asserts that Commerce incorrectly calculated the margin by not
accounting for differences in the color and, therefore, the price of certain
products. According to Cinsa, Commerce used the five digit product code,
rather than the seven digit product code, and thereby failed to account
for differences in product color. The five digit code identifies the product.
The additional two digits identify the product color. Cinsa further contends
that the administrative record contains information from which Commerce
could have identified product color differences.
In its initial questionnaire response, and consistent with its position
in the fourth administrative review, Cinsa informed Commerce that it should
rely upon the five digit product code instead of the seven digit product
code. Cinsa explained then that color differences did not significantly
alter product cost. Thus, Cinsa reported to Commerce that "[o]nce the number
of enamel coatings is taken into account, fair value comparisons may be
made without regard to color."
Later, on December 31, 1992, Cinsa wrote to Commerce seeking to change
this position. Cinsa asked Commerce to compare "type, size, number of enamel
coatings and the color of the article in its model matching criteria,"
explaining that "upon further review of the cost and pricing information
contained in the questionnaire response, Cinsa has determined that the
price and cost differences between articles of the same size and number
of enamel coatings, but of different colors, are greater than de minimus."
(Emphasis in original.) Cinsa requested that Commerce account for color
differences, or, "to the extent that contemporaneous identical matches
of same-colored merchandise cannot be made," that Commerce "make similar
merchandise comparisons using an article of the same type, size and number
of enamel coatings but of a different color, with an adjustment made to
account for the cost differences as reported in the COP tape."
The comparisons Commerce used in its preliminary results did not account
or adjust for product color differences. Cinsa filed a lengthy administrative
case brief in response to the preliminary results, raising many issues,
and presented lengthy oral argument to Commerce. Nowhere did Cinsa raise
with Commerce the alleged error in failing to account for product color
differences. Cinsa did not raise the issue until its appeal to this panel.
At oral argument, Cinsa’s counsel explained that Cinsa did not realize
that Commerce had not accounted for color differences. Cinsa argued that
Commerce stated in its preliminary decision that Commerce had compared
identical products, and therefore Cinsa assumed that this meant that Commerce
had accounted for product color differences:
"And the question of whether or not the DOC made identical model matches,
we didn’t focus on because, according to their memorandum, they did do
that. We had no reason not to believe they did what they told us in the
disclosure of what they were doing. That’s the practical answer to what
happened between why it wasn’t raised at the preliminary stage."
Cinsa also admits that information in the record reflects that the five
digit code was used, rather than the seven digit code. But, according to
Cinsa, "it took us time to go through" the information and to simulate
the computer program to discover the discrepancy. The crux of the problem
apparently was that Cinsa was not focused on the issue at the time. Instead,
Cinsa concentrated on determining the reasons for the disparity between
the anti-dumping margins arising from earlier administrative reviews and
the anti-dumping margin arising here. It appears that Cinsa simply did
not notice the problem until the current appeal.
Cinsa asserts that, given this record, Commerce should be faulted for
using the five digit code, rather than the seven digit code, in its final
results. The Panel disagrees. Cinsa was timely in informing Commerce that
product color differences should be taken into account. But when Cinsa
failed to raise the Department’s failure to do so in response to the preliminary
results, Cinsa waived its right to assert that such failure was error.
Commerce cannot be held in error for using the five digit code in its final
results when Cinsa did not raise the issue in response to the preliminary
results. See, e.g., Koyo Seiko Co. v. United States, 768 F. Supp. 832 (Ct.
Int’l Trade 1991), aff’d, 972 F.2d 1355 (Fed. Cir. 1992) (party failed
to exhaust its administrative remedies when it raised issue by letter early
in proceedings but failed to raise issue again in administrative proceedings);
Timken Co. v. United States, 795 F. Supp. 438, 443 (Ct. Int’l Trade 1992)
(party is required "to specifically contest at the administrative level
those choices with which it did not agree"). Cinsa’s contentions that this
alleged error is a "purely legal" one, or alternatively that it could not
have sooner identified the alleged error, are both unconvincing. While
Commerce is statutorily directed to compare identical products, how it
does so in any particular case is a factual matter. The use of the five
digit product code instead of the seven digit product code is not a matter
of interpreting a statute or deciding upon a legal standard. It is, rather,
purely factual. Cinsa had all of the information it needed to raise this
alleged error when it presented its problems with the Department’s preliminary
results.
Cinsa had an obligation to raise with Commerce all substantive issues
known at the time which Cinsa asserts contributed to an allegedly unfair
price comparison. This is especially true when, as here, Cinsa’s position
on the particular assertion is directly contrary to the position submitted
to Commerce in prior reviews and in Cinsa’s initial questionnaire response.
Because Cinsa waived this issue during the course of the administrative
proceeding, this Panel will not consider whether Commerce should have used
the seven digit product code instead of the five digit product code in
establishing its model matching criteria. 9
6. Error Associated with Product Number 10158
In its administrative case brief in response to the preliminary results,
Cinsa pointed out to Commerce that Cinsa had reported standard costs for
certain items in a way that inappropriately skewed the figures for that
item. Cinsa requested that Commerce account for its error when issuing
the final results. Commerce declined. The Panel finds that Commerce erred
in not accounting for the error, and direct Commerce on remand to recalculate
in accordance with this opinion.
Commerce had required Cinsa to report costs on a per-unit basis. In
general, Cinsa reported its costs on a per-box basis. But in those instances
where Cinsa sold its products in boxes containing multiple units, as opposed
to single units, Cinsa’s standard cost accounting reported each box as
a single unit. According to Cinsa, "in order to conform to the DOC’s request
to report only single unit costs, in cases where more than one item was
packed in a box, Cinsa divided the total cost of the items sold in multiple
packaged units by the number of items in the package." Prior to the preliminary
determination, Cinsa discovered that it had not made that division for
certain items and informed Commerce by letter of its error. Commerce corrected
its data in accordance with the method that Cinsa suggested. In reviewing
the preliminary results, Cinsa discovered another such error and raised
it in its administrative case brief. Commerce, however, declined to alter
its findings to account for this error. Commerce and General Housewares
assert that there was not enough evidence in the administrative record
from which Commerce could recalculate the claim and that Cinsa’s request
therefore came too late. Commerce and General Housewares do not contend
that Cinsa’s position is flawed, but rather that Cinsa presented it too
late.
The administrative record contained information indicating that Item
# 10158 (1 quart sauce pan package with multiple units) differed from Item
# 10166 (1 quart sauce pan package with single unit) because the reported
weight was different by .092 kilograms (.348 kg vs. .440 kgs). Commerce
contends that it cannot know the cost differential associated with the
different items without knowing the packaging costs associated with the
single unit item versus the multiple unit item. Thus, according to Commerce,
the error had to be corrected within the time for submission of new factual
information.
Cinsa, on the other hand, contends that no new factual information was
required to fix the error. According to Cinsa, Commerce could correct the
COP/CV data error by dividing the reported costs for these items by two—just
as it did with the other errors brought to its attention before the preliminary
results. Thus, Cinsa asserts that its failure to discover its mistake before
the deadline for submission of factual information has no impact on Commerce’s
ability to correct for the error.
The Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit recently addressed a similar
situation in NTN Bearing Corp. v. United States 74 F.3d 1204 (Fed. Cir.
1995). In that case, the Federal Circuit made clear that Commerce may account
for untimely factual information about inadvertent clerical errors, when
to do so does not require starting anew or delaying the final determination.
74 F.3d at 1208. The case also raises the possibility that Commerce abuses
its discretion when it fails to allow a respondent to present untimely,
new factual information that would correct an error, even when such an
error is not obvious from the record that existed before the preliminary
determination.
The Panel believes that the NTN Bearing case is controlling here and
that it sets the minimum standards for the untimely submission of factual
information necessary to correct a clerical error. On remand, Commerce
should consider whether Cinsa’s suggestion of simply dividing by two the
costs of producing Item # 10158 is sufficient (as it apparently was with
the other multiple unit products brought to Commerce’s attention) or whether
Commerce needs Cinsa to present data relating to packaging costs. In either
event, Commerce should account for the cost differential associated with
the difference between a single-unit and a multi-unit package for 1 quart
sauce pans. The Panel remands this issue to the Department for further
proceedings consistent with this opinion.
Continue on to Section IV: Conclusion
3 In countervailing-duty
cases, Commerce has adopted a methodology for classifying hybrid instruments
as debt or equity, and this methodology was recently upheld by the Court
of International Trade. Geneva Steel v. United States, No. 93-09-00566-CVD,
1996 WL 19112, at *3 (Ct. Int’l Trade Jan. 3, 1996). Recognizing that many
payments could share characteristics of both debt and equity, Commerce
set forth a four-tiered hierarchy of considerations. These factors are:
1) expiration/maturity date/repayment obligation, (2) guaranteed interest
or dividends, (3) ownership rights, and (4) seniority. Id.
4 Income taxes and mandatory
profit-sharing payments are also alike in that both reduce a firm’s return
on equity, thus increasing the firm’s costs of capital and, in time, the
firm’s marginal cost. Prices of corporate goods may rise as a result, and
output may also be affected. See Douglas R. Fletcher, The International
Argument for Corporate Tax Integration, 11 Am. J. Tax Policy 155, 160 &
n.19 (1994); D.A. Auld and F.C. Miller, Principles of Public Finance 111
(2d ed. 1975); Augh Gravelle & Ray Reese, Microeconomics 244-45 (2d
ed. 1992). The net effect on price and quantity will depend on the elasticities
of supply and demand. Fletcher at 10 & n.19.
5 In its brief, Cinsa argues
that profit-sharing should not be included in CV because it is not a cost
"incurred prior to exportation" as required by 19 U.S.C.A. § 1677b(e)(1).
(1994 & Supp. 1996). In light of the fact that the current version
of that statute does not contain this language, as well as the fact that
Cinsa did not raise this argument in the administrative review, we decline
to consider this issue.
6 In Floral Trade Council
v. United States, 775 F. Supp. 1492, 1504 (Ct. Int’l Trade 1991), the court
acknowledged the Department’s policy of allowing "interest income if that
income is earned from short-term investments related to current operations
of the company." It did not discuss the reasoning behind the policy other
than to recognize that interest income cannot be considered unless it is
related to production of the merchandise in question.
7 E.g., Small Diameter
Circular Seamless Carbon And Alloy Steel, Standard, Line and Pressure Pipe
From Italy, 60 Fed. Reg. 31,981, 31,991 (1995);Frozen Concentrated Orange
Juice From Brazil, 55 Fed. Reg. 26,721 (1990); Brass Sheet and Strip From
Canada, 55 Fed. Reg. 31,414, 31,416 (1990); Sweaters Wholly or in Chief
Weight of Man-Made Fiber From Taiwan, 55 Fed. Reg. 34,585, 34,599 (1990)("We
do not offset other elements of G&A expenses with interest income for
purposes of calculating CV."); Titanium Sponge from Japan, 52 Fed. Reg.
4797, 4799 (1987) (Comment 17).
8 As amended by the Uruguay
Round Agreements Act, the statute now excludes taxes from normal value.
19 U.S.C. § 1677b(a)(6)(B) (1994 & Supp. 1996). The amendment
was not in effect for the review before this Panel.
9 On March 26, 1996, Cinsa
informed the Panel that the Department had recently reached preliminary
determinations in the sixth and eighth administrative reviews of the antidumping
duty order on Porcelain-on-Steel Cooking Ware from Mexico. Copies of those
results were submitted to the Panel with a request that we take notice
of the fact that the Department considered product color in making model
matches in both reviews. Decisions in these subsequent reviews do not,
however, negate Cinsa’s waiver of this issue with respect to the present
review under consideration.
|